Economics Of Attention Pdf Merge Average ratng: 5,0/5 230 reviews

The Economics of Attention: Style and Substance in the Age of Information. The Economics of Attention should be considered 'important' for its ability to continue the discourse of what social. Managing Tourism at World Heritage Sites: a Practical Manual for World Heritage Site Managers By Arthur Pedersen WH • manual1-intro 31/10/02 14:02 Page 1. The Economics of Attention Politicians, journalists, marketers, the entertainment industry, even educators and the clergy: everyone wants our attention. Increasingly, attention is considered to be a form of capital. Some economists argue that attention in fact constitutes a parallel economy run on a virtual currency.

(Redirected from Merger)
Corporate finance
Working capital
Sections
Societal components

Mergers and acquisitions (M&A) are transactions in which the ownership of companies, other business organizations, or their operating units are transferred or consolidated with other entities. As an aspect of strategic management, M&A can allow enterprises to grow or downsize, and change the nature of their business or competitive position.

From a legal point of view, a merger is a legal consolidation of two entities into one entity, whereas an acquisition occurs when one entity takes ownership of another entity's stock, equity interests or assets. From a commercial and economic point of view, both types of transactions generally result in the consolidation of assets and liabilities under one entity, and the distinction between a 'merger' and an 'acquisition' is less clear. A transaction legally structured as an acquisition may have the effect of placing one party's business under the indirect ownership of the other party's shareholders, while a transaction legally structured as a merger may give each party's shareholders partial ownership and control of the combined enterprise. A deal may be euphemistically called a merger of equals if both CEOs agree that joining together is in the best interest of both of their companies, while when the deal is unfriendly (that is, when the management of the target company opposes the deal) it may be regarded as an 'acquisition'.

  • 5Financing
  • 7Motivation
  • 8Different types
  • 11History
    • 11.1The Great Merger Movement: 1895–1905
  • 12Cross-border

Acquisition[edit]

An acquisition/takeover is the purchase of one business or company by another company or other business entity. Specific acquisition targets can be identified through myriad avenues including market research, trade expos, sent up from internal business units, or supply chain analysis.[1][2] Such purchase may be of 100%, or nearly 100%, of the assets or ownership equity of the acquired entity. Consolidation/amalgamation occurs when two companies combine to form a new enterprise altogether, and neither of the previous companies remains independently. Acquisitions are divided into 'private' and 'public' acquisitions, depending on whether the acquiree or merging company (also termed a target) is or is not listed on a public stock market. Some public companies rely on acquisitions as an important value creation strategy.[3] An additional dimension or categorization consists of whether an acquisition is friendly or hostile.

Achieving acquisition success has proven to be very difficult, while various studies have shown that 50% of acquisitions were unsuccessful.[4] 'Serial acquirers' appear to be more successful with M&A than companies who make an acquisition only occasionally (see Douma & Schreuder, 2013, chapter 13). The new forms of buy out created since the crisis are based on serial type acquisitions known as an ECO Buyout which is a co-community ownership buy out and the new generation buy outs of the MIBO (Management Involved or Management & Institution Buy Out) and MEIBO (Management & Employee Involved Buy Out).

Look up merger in Wiktionary, the free dictionary.

Whether a purchase is perceived as being a 'friendly' one or 'hostile' depends significantly on how the proposed acquisition is communicated to and perceived by the target company's board of directors, employees and shareholders. It is normal for M&A deal communications to take place in a so-called 'confidentiality bubble' wherein the flow of information is restricted pursuant to confidentiality agreements.[5] In the case of a friendly transaction, the companies cooperate in negotiations; in the case of a hostile deal, the board and/or management of the target is unwilling to be bought or the target's board has no prior knowledge of the offer. Hostile acquisitions can, and often do, ultimately become 'friendly', as the acquiror secures endorsement of the transaction from the board of the acquiree company. This usually requires an improvement in the terms of the offer and/or through negotiation.

'Acquisition' usually refers to a purchase of a smaller firm by a larger one. Sometimes, however, a smaller firm will acquire management control of a larger and/or longer-established company and retain the name of the latter for the post-acquisition combined entity. This is known as a reverse takeover. Another type of acquisition is the reverse merger, a form of transaction that enables a private company to be publicly listed in a relatively short time frame. A reverse merger occurs when a privately held company (often one that has strong prospects and is eager to raise financing) buys a publicly listed shell company, usually one with no business and limited assets.

The combined evidence suggests that the shareholders of acquired firms realize significant positive 'abnormal returns' while shareholders of the acquiring company are most likely to experience a negative wealth effect.[6] The overall net effect of M&A transactions appears to be positive: almost all studies report positive returns for the investors in the combined buyer and target firms. This implies that M&A creates economic value, presumably by transferring assets to management teams that operate them more efficiently (see Douma & Schreuder, 2013, chapter 13).

There are also a variety of structures used in securing control over the assets of a company, which have different tax and regulatory implications:

  • The buyer buys the shares, and therefore control, of the target company being purchased. Ownership control of the company in turn conveys effective control over the assets of the company, but since the company is acquired intact as a going concern, this form of transaction carries with it all of the liabilities accrued by that business over its past and all of the risks that company faces in its commercial environment.
  • The buyer buys the assets of the target company. The cash the target receives from the sell-off is paid back to its shareholders by dividend or through liquidation. This type of transaction leaves the target company as an empty shell, if the buyer buys out the entire assets. A buyer often structures the transaction as an asset purchase to 'cherry-pick' the assets that it wants and leave out the assets and liabilities that it does not. This can be particularly important where foreseeable liabilities may include future, unquantified damage awards such as those that could arise from litigation over defective products, employee benefits or terminations, or environmental damage. A disadvantage of this structure is the tax that many jurisdictions, particularly outside the United States, impose on transfers of the individual assets, whereas stock transactions can frequently be structured as like-kind exchanges or other arrangements that are tax-free or tax-neutral, both to the buyer and to the seller's shareholders.

The terms 'demerger', 'spin-off' and 'spin-out' are sometimes used to indicate a situation where one company splits into two, generating a second company which may or may not become separately listed on a stock exchange.

As per knowledge-based views, firms can generate greater values through the retention of knowledge-based resources which they generate and integrate.[7] Extracting technological benefits during and after acquisition is ever challenging issue because of organizational differences. Based on the content analysis of seven interviews authors concluded five following components for their grounded model of acquisition:

  1. Improper documentation and changing implicit knowledge makes it difficult to share information during acquisition.
  2. For acquired firm symbolic and cultural independence which is the base of technology and capabilities are more important than administrative independence.
  3. Detailed knowledge exchange and integrations are difficult when the acquired firm is large and high performing.
  4. Management of executives from acquired firm is critical in terms of promotions and pay incentives to utilize their talent and value their expertise.
  5. Transfer of technologies and capabilities are most difficult task to manage because of complications of acquisition implementation. The risk of losing implicit knowledge is always associated with the fast pace acquisition.

An increase in acquisitions in the global business environment requires enterprises to evaluate the key stake holders of acquisition very carefully before implementation. It is imperative for the acquirer to understand this relationship and apply it to its advantage. Employee retention is possible only when resources are exchanged and managed without affecting their independence.[8]

Legal structures[edit]

Corporate acquisitions can be characterized for legal purposes as either 'asset purchases' in which the seller sells business assets to the buyer, or 'equity purchases' in which the buyer purchases equity interests in a target company from one or more selling shareholders. Asset purchases are common in technology transactions where the buyer is most interested in particular intellectual property rights but does not want to acquire liabilities or other contractual relationships.[9] An asset purchase structure may also be used when the buyer wishes to buy a particular division or unit of a company which is not a separate legal entity. There are numerous challenges particular to this type of transaction, including isolating the specific assets and liabilities that pertain to the unit, determining whether the unit utilizes services from other units of the selling company, transferring employees, transferring permits and licenses, and ensuring that the seller does not compete with the buyer in the same business area in the future.[10]

Structuring the sale of a financially distressed company is uniquely difficult due to the treatment of non-compete covenants, consulting agreements, and business goodwill in such transactions.

Mergers, asset purchases and equity purchases are each taxed differently, and the most beneficial structure for tax purposes is highly situation-dependent. One hybrid form often employed for tax purposes is a triangular merger, where the target company merges with a shell company wholly owned by the buyer, thus becoming a subsidiary of the buyer. In a 'forward triangular merger', the buyer causes the target company to merge into the subsidiary; a 'reverse triangular merger' is similar except that the subsidiary merges into the target company. Under the U.S. Internal Revenue Code, a forward triangular merger is taxed as if the target company sold its assets to the shell company and then liquidated, whereas a reverse triangular merger is taxed as if the target company's shareholders sold their stock in the target company to the buyer.[11]

Documentation[edit]

Merger

The documentation of an M&A transaction often begins with a letter of intent. The letter of intent generally does not bind the parties to commit to a transaction, but may bind the parties to confidentiality and exclusivity obligations so that the transaction can be considered through a due diligence process involving lawyers, accountants, tax advisors, and other professionals, as well as business people from both sides.[10]

After due diligence is complete, the parties may proceed to draw up a definitive agreement, known as a 'merger agreement', 'share purchase agreement' or 'asset purchase agreement' depending on the structure of the transaction. Such contracts are typically 80 to 100 pages long and focus on five key types of terms:[12]

  • Conditions, which must be satisfied before there is an obligation to complete the transaction. Conditions typically include matters such as regulatory approvals and the lack of any material adverse change in the target's business.
  • Representations and warranties by the seller with regard to the company, which are claimed to be true at both the time of signing and the time of closing. Sellers often attempt to craft their representations and warranties with knowledge qualifiers, dictating the level of knowledge applicable and which seller parties' knowledge is relevant. Some agreements provide that if the representations and warranties by the seller prove to be false, the buyer may claim a refund of part of the purchase price, as is common in transactions involving privately held companies (although in most acquisition agreements involving public company targets, the representations and warranties of the seller do not survive the closing). Representations regarding a target company's net working capital are a common source of post-closing disputes.
  • Covenants, which govern the conduct of the parties, both before the closing (such as covenants that restrict the operations of the business between signing and closing) and after the closing (such as covenants regarding future income tax filings and tax liability or post-closing restrictions agreed to by the buyer and seller parties).
  • Termination rights, which may be triggered by a breach of contract, a failure to satisfy certain conditions or the passage of a certain period of time without consummating the transaction, and fees and damages payable in case of a termination for certain events (also known as breakup fees).
  • Provisions relating to obtaining required shareholder approvals under state law and related SEC filings required under federal law, if applicable, and terms related to the mechanics of the legal transactions to be consummated at closing (such as the determination and allocation of the purchase price and post-closing adjustments (such as adjustments after the final determination of working capital at closing or earnout payments payable to the sellers), repayment of outstanding debt, and the treatment of outstanding shares, options and other equity interests).
  • An indemnification provision, which provides that an indemnitor will indemnify, defend, and hold harmless the indemnitee(s) for losses incurred by the indemnitees as a result of the indemnitor's breach of its contractual obligations in the purchase agreement

Post-closing, adjustments may still occur to certain provisions of the purchase agreement, including the purchase price. These adjustments are subject to enforceability issues in certain situations. Alternatively, certain transactions use the 'locked box' approach where the purchase price is fixed at signing and based on seller’s equity value at a pre-signing date and an interest charge.

Business valuation[edit]

The five most common ways to value a business are

  • asset valuation,
  • historical earnings valuation,
  • future maintainable earnings valuation,
  • relative valuation (comparable company and comparable transactions),
  • discounted cash flow (DCF) valuation

Professionals who value businesses generally do not use just one method but a combination

Most often value is expressed in a Letter of Opinion of Value (LOV) when the business is being valued informally. Formal valuation reports generally get more detailed and expensive as the size of a company increases, but this is not always the case as the nature of the business and the industry it is operating in can influence the complexity of the valuation task.

Attention

Objectively evaluating the historical and prospective performance of a business is a challenge faced by many. Generally, parties rely on independent third parties to conduct due diligence studies or business assessments. To yield the most value from a business assessment, objectives should be clearly defined and the right resources should be chosen to conduct the assessment in the available timeframe.

As synergy plays a large role in the valuation of acquisitions, it is paramount to get the value of synergies right. Synergies are different from the 'sales price' valuation of the firm, as they will accrue to the buyer. Hence, the analysis should be done from the acquiring firm's point of view. Synergy-creating investments are started by the choice of the acquirer, and therefore they are not obligatory, making them essentially real options. To include this real options aspect into analysis of acquisition targets is one interesting issue that has been studied lately.[13]

Financing[edit]

Part of a series on
Accounting
  • Depreciation / Amortization
  • Ledger / General ledger

Mergers are generally differentiated from acquisitions partly by the way in which they are financed and partly by the relative size of the companies. Various methods of financing an M&A deal exist:

Cash[edit]

Payment by cash. Such transactions are usually termed acquisitions rather than mergers because the shareholders of the target company are removed from the picture and the target comes under the (indirect) control of the bidder's shareholders.

Stock[edit]

Payment in the form of the acquiring company's stock, issued to the shareholders of the acquired company at a given ratio proportional to the valuation of the latter. They receive stock in the company that is purchasing the smaller subsidiary.

Financing options[edit]

There are some elements to think about when choosing the form of payment. When submitting an offer, the acquiring firm should consider other potential bidders and think strategically. The form of payment might be decisive for the seller. With pure cash deals, there is no doubt on the real value of the bid (without considering an eventual earnout). The contingency of the share payment is indeed removed. Thus, a cash offer preempts competitors better than securities. Taxes are a second element to consider and should be evaluated with the counsel of competent tax and accounting advisers. Third, with a share deal the buyer’s capital structure might be affected and the control of the buyer modified. If the issuance of shares is necessary, shareholders of the acquiring company might prevent such capital increase at the general meeting of shareholders. The risk is removed with a cash transaction. Then, the balance sheet of the buyer will be modified and the decision maker should take into account the effects on the reported financial results. For example, in a pure cash deal (financed from the company’s current account), liquidity ratios might decrease. On the other hand, in a pure stock for stock transaction (financed from the issuance of new shares), the company might show lower profitability ratios (e.g. ROA). However, economic dilution must prevail towards accounting dilution when making the choice. The form of payment and financing options are tightly linked. If the buyer pays cash, there are three main financing options:

  • Cash on hand: it consumes financial slack (excess cash or unused debt capacity) and may decrease debt rating. There are no major transaction costs.
  • Issue of debt: It consumes financial slack, may decrease debt rating and increase cost of debt. Transaction costs include underwriting or closing costs of 1% to 3% of the face value.
  • Issue of stock: it increases financial slack, may improve debt rating and reduce cost of debt. Transaction costs include fees for preparation of a proxy statement, an extraordinary shareholder meeting and registration.

If the buyer pays with stock, the financing possibilities are:

  • Issue of stock (same effects and transaction costs as described above).
  • Shares in treasury: it increases financial slack (if they don’t have to be repurchased on the market), may improve debt rating and reduce cost of debt. Transaction costs include brokerage fees if shares are repurchased in the market otherwise there are no major costs.

In general, stock will create financial flexibility. Transaction costs must also be considered but tend to affect the payment decision more for larger transactions. Finally, paying cash or with shares is a way to signal value to the other party, e.g.: buyers tend to offer stock when they believe their shares are overvalued and cash when undervalued.

Economics Of Attention Pdf Merger

Parties should also consider their accounting treatment of M&A transaction costs and ensure they comply with Department of Treasury regulations, including the applicability of the 'end of the day' and 'next day' rules.

Specialist advisory firms[edit]

M&A advice is provided by full-service investment banks- who often advise and handle the biggest deals in the world (called bulge bracket) - and specialist M&A firms, who provide M&A only advisory, generally to mid-market, select industries and SBEs.

Highly focused and specialized M&A advice investment banks are called boutique investment banks.

Motivation[edit]

Improving financial performance or reducing risk[edit]

The dominant rationale used to explain M&A activity is that acquiring firms seek improved financial performance or reduce risk. The following motives are considered to improve financial performance or reduce risk:

  • Economy of scale: This refers to the fact that the combined company can often reduce its fixed costs by removing duplicate departments or operations, lowering the costs of the company relative to the same revenue stream, thus increasing profit margins.
  • Economy of scope: This refers to the efficiencies primarily associated with demand-side changes, such as increasing or decreasing the scope of marketing and distribution, of different types of products.
  • Increased revenue or market share: This assumes that the buyer will be absorbing a major competitor and thus increase its market power (by capturing increased market share) to set prices.
  • Cross-selling: For example, a bank buying a stock broker could then sell its banking products to the stock broker's customers, while the broker can sign up the bank's customers for brokerage accounts. Or, a manufacturer can acquire and sell complementary products.
  • Synergy: For example, managerial economies such as the increased opportunity of managerial specialization. Another example is purchasing economies due to increased order size and associated bulk-buying discounts.
  • Taxation: A profitable company can buy a loss maker to use the target's loss as their advantage by reducing their tax liability. In the United States and many other countries, rules are in place to limit the ability of profitable companies to 'shop' for loss making companies, limiting the tax motive of an acquiring company.
  • Geographical or other diversification: This is designed to smooth the earnings results of a company, which over the long term smoothens the stock price of a company, giving conservative investors more confidence in investing in the company. However, this does not always deliver value to shareholders (see below).
  • Resource transfer: resources are unevenly distributed across firms (Barney, 1991) and the interaction of target and acquiring firm resources can create value through either overcoming information asymmetry or by combining scarce resources.[14]
  • Vertical integration: Vertical integration occurs when an upstream and downstream firm merge (or one acquires the other). There are several reasons for this to occur. One reason is to internalise an externality problem. A common example of such an externality is double marginalization. Double marginalization occurs when both the upstream and downstream firms have monopoly power and each firm reduces output from the competitive level to the monopoly level, creating two deadweight losses. After a merger, the vertically integrated firm can collect one deadweight loss by setting the downstream firm's output to the competitive level. This increases profits and consumer surplus. A merger that creates a vertically integrated firm can be profitable.[15]
  • Hiring: some companies use acquisitions as an alternative to the normal hiring process. This is especially common when the target is a small private company or is in the startup phase. In this case, the acquiring company simply hires ('acquhires') the staff of the target private company, thereby acquiring its talent (if that is its main asset and appeal). The target private company simply dissolves and few legal issues are involved.[citation needed]
  • Absorption of similar businesses under single management: similar portfolio invested by two different mutual funds namely united money market fund and united growth and income fund, caused the management to absorb united money market fund into united growth and income fund.
  • Access to hidden or nonperforming assets (land, real estate).
  • Acquire innovative intellectual property. Nowadays, intellectual property has become one of the core competences for companies.[16] Studies have shown that successful knowledge transfer and integration after a merger or acquisition has a positive impact to the firm's innovative capability and performance.[17]

Megadeals—deals of at least one $1 billion in size—tend to fall into four discrete categories: consolidation, capabilities extension, technology-driven market transformation, and going private.

Other types[edit]

However, on average and across the most commonly studied variables, acquiring firms' financial performance does not positively change as a function of their acquisition activity.[18] Therefore, additional motives for merger and acquisition that may not add shareholder value include:

  • Diversification: While this may hedge a company against a downturn in an individual industry it fails to deliver value, since it is possible for individual shareholders to achieve the same hedge by diversifying their portfolios at a much lower cost than those associated with a merger. (In his book One Up on Wall Street, Peter Lynch termed this 'diworseification'.)
  • Manager's hubris: manager's overconfidence about expected synergies from M&A which results in overpayment for the target company.
  • Empire-building: Managers have larger companies to manage and hence more power.
  • Manager's compensation: In the past, certain executive management teams had their payout based on the total amount of profit of the company, instead of the profit per share, which would give the team a perverse incentive to buy companies to increase the total profit while decreasing the profit per share (which hurts the owners of the company, the shareholders).

Different types[edit]

By functional roles in market[edit]

The M&A process itself is a multifaceted which depends upon the type of merging companies.

  • A horizontal merger is usually between two companies in the same business sector. An example of horizontal merger would be if a video game publisher purchases another video game publisher, for instance, Square Enix acquiring Eidos Interactive.[19] This means that synergy can be obtained through many forms such as; increased market share, cost savings and exploring new market opportunities.
  • A vertical merger represents the buying of supplier of a business. In a similar example, if a video game publisher purchases a video game development company in order to retain the development studio's intellectual properties, for instance, Kadokawa Corporation acquiring FromSoftware.[20] The vertical buying is aimed at reducing overhead cost of operations and economy of scale.
  • Conglomerate M&A is the third form of M&A process which deals the merger between two irrelevant companies. The relevant example of conglomerate M&A would be if a video game publisher purchases an animation studio, for instance, when Sega Sammy Holdings subsidized TMS Entertainment.[21] The objective is often diversification of goods and services and capital investment.

By business outcome[edit]

The M&A process results in the restructuring of a business' purpose, corporate governance and brand identity.

  • A statutory merger is a merger in which the acquiring company survives and the target company dissolves. The purpose of this merger is to transfer the assets and capital of the target company into the acquiring company without having to maintain the target company as a subsidiary.[22]
  • A consolidated merger is a merger in which an entirely new legal company is formed through combining the acquiring and target company. The purpose of this merger is to create a new legal entity with the capital and assets of the merged acquirer and target company. Both the acquiring and target company are dissolved in the process.[22]

Arm's length mergers[edit]

An arm's length merger is a merger:

  1. approved by disinterested directors and
  2. approved by disinterested stockholders:

″The two elements are complementary and not substitutes. The first element is important because the directors have the capability to act as effective and active bargaining agents, which disaggregated stockholders do not. But, because bargaining agents are not always effective or faithful, the second element is critical, because it gives the minority stockholders the opportunity to reject their agents' work. Therefore, when a merger with a controlling stockholder was: 1) negotiated and approved by a special committee of independent directors; and 2) conditioned on an affirmative vote of a majority of the minority stockholders, the business judgment standard of review should presumptively apply, and any plaintiff ought to have to plead particularized facts that, if true, support an inference that, despite the facially fair process, the merger was tainted because of fiduciary wrongdoing.″[23]

Strategic mergers[edit]

A Strategic merger usually refers to long term strategic holding of target (Acquired) firm. This type of M&A process aims at creating synergies in the long run by increased market share, broad customer base, and corporate strength of business. A strategic acquirer may also be willing to pay a premium offer to target firm in the outlook of the synergy value created after M&A process.

Acqui-hire[edit]

The term 'acqui-hire' is used to refer to acquisitions where the acquiring company seeks to obtain the target company's talent, rather than their products (which are often discontinued as part of the acquisition so the team can focus on projects for their new employer). In recent years, these types of acquisitions have become common in the technology industry, where major web companies such as Facebook, Twitter, and Yahoo! have frequently used talent acquisitions to add expertise in particular areas to their workforces.[24][25]

Merger of equals[edit]

Merger of equals is often a combination of companies of a similar size. Since 1990, there have been more than 625 M&A transactions announced as mergers of equals with a total value of USD 2,164.4 bil.[26] Some of the largest mergers of equals took place during the dot.com bubble of the late 1990s and in the year 2000: AOL and Time Warner (USD 164 bil.), SmithKline Beecham and Glaxo Wellcome (USD 75 bil.), Citicorp and Travelers Group (USD 72 bil.). More recent examples this type of combinations are DuPont and Dow Chemical (USD 62 bil.) and Praxair and Linde (USD 35 bil.).

Research and statistics for acquired organizations[edit]

An analysis of 1,600 companies across industries revealed the rewards for M&A activity were greater for consumer products companies than the average company. For the period 2000-2010, consumer products companies turned in an average annual TSR of 7.4%, while the average for all companies was 4.8%.

Given that the cost of replacing an executive can run over 100% of his or her annual salary, any investment of time and energy in re-recruitment will likely pay for itself many times over if it helps a business retain just a handful of key players that would have otherwise left.

Organizations should move rapidly to re-recruit key managers. It’s much easier to succeed with a team of quality players that one selects deliberately rather than try to win a game with those who randomly show up to play.

Brand considerations[edit]

Mergers and acquisitions often create brand problems, beginning with what to call the company after the transaction and going down into detail about what to do about overlapping and competing product brands. Decisions about what brand equity to write off are not inconsequential. And, given the ability for the right brand choices to drive preference and earn a price premium, the future success of a merger or acquisition depends on making wise brand choices. Brand decision-makers essentially can choose from four different approaches to dealing with naming issues, each with specific pros and cons:[27]

  1. Keep one name and discontinue the other. The strongest legacy brand with the best prospects for the future lives on. In the merger of United Airlines and Continental Airlines, the United brand will continue forward, while Continental is retired.
  2. Keep one name and demote the other. The strongest name becomes the company name and the weaker one is demoted to a divisional brand or product brand. An example is Caterpillar Inc. keeping the Bucyrus International name.[28]
  3. Keep both names and use them together. Some companies try to please everyone and keep the value of both brands by using them together. This can create an unwieldy name, as in the case of PricewaterhouseCoopers, which has since changed its brand name to 'PwC'.
  4. Discard both legacy names and adopt a totally new one. The classic example is the merger of Bell Atlantic with GTE, which became Verizon Communications. Not every merger with a new name is successful. By consolidating into YRC Worldwide, the company lost the considerable value of both Yellow Freight and Roadway Corp.

The factors influencing brand decisions in a merger or acquisition transaction can range from political to tactical. Ego can drive choice just as well as rational factors such as brand value and costs involved with changing brands.[28]

Beyond the bigger issue of what to call the company after the transaction comes the ongoing detailed choices about what divisional, product and service brands to keep. The detailed decisions about the brand portfolio are covered under the topic brand architecture.

History[edit]

Replica of an East Indiaman of the Dutch East India Company/United East India Company (VOC). A pioneering early model of the public company and multinational corporation in its modern sense, the VOC was formed in 1602 from a government-directedconsolidation/amalgamation of several competing Dutch trading companies (the so-called voorcompagnieën). It was possibly in fact the first recorded major consolidation[29][30] and is generally one of the most successful mergers (in particular amalgamations) in the history of business.[31]

Most histories of M&A begin in the late 19th century United States. However, mergers coincide historically with the existence of companies. Download removewat windows 7 terbaru aurelia. In 1708, for example, the East India Company merged with an erstwhile competitor to restore its monopoly over the Indian trade. In 1784, the Italian Monte dei Paschi and Monte Pio banks were united as the Monti Reuniti.[32] In 1821, the Hudson's Bay Company merged with the rival North West Company.

The Great Merger Movement: 1895–1905[edit]

The Great Merger Movement was a predominantly U.S. business phenomenon that happened from 1895 to 1905. During this time, small firms with little market share consolidated with similar firms to form large, powerful institutions that dominated their markets. It is estimated that more than 1,800 of these firms disappeared into consolidations, many of which acquired substantial shares of the markets in which they operated. The vehicle used were so-called trusts. In 1900 the value of firms acquired in mergers was 20% of GDP. In 1990 the value was only 3% and from 1998 to 2000 it was around 10–11% of GDP. Companies such as DuPont, U.S. Steel, and General Electric that merged during the Great Merger Movement were able to keep their dominance in their respective sectors through 1929, and in some cases today, due to growing technological advances of their products, patents, and brand recognition by their customers. There were also other companies that held the greatest market share in 1905 but at the same time did not have the competitive advantages of the companies like DuPont and General Electric. These companies such as International Paper and American Chicle saw their market share decrease significantly by 1929 as smaller competitors joined forces with each other and provided much more competition. The companies that merged were mass producers of homogeneous goods that could exploit the efficiencies of large volume production. In addition, many of these mergers were capital-intensive. Due to high fixed costs, when demand fell, these newly merged companies had an incentive to maintain output and reduce prices. However more often than not mergers were 'quick mergers'. These 'quick mergers' involved mergers of companies with unrelated technology and different management. As a result, the efficiency gains associated with mergers were not present. The new and bigger company would actually face higher costs than competitors because of these technological and managerial differences. Thus, the mergers were not done to see large efficiency gains, they were in fact done because that was the trend at the time. Companies which had specific fine products, like fine writing paper, earned their profits on high margin rather than volume and took no part in the Great Merger Movement.[citation needed]

Short-run factors[edit]

One of the major short run factors that sparked the Great Merger Movement was the desire to keep prices high. However, high prices attracted the entry of new firms into the industry.

A major catalyst behind the Great Merger Movement was the Panic of 1893, which led to a major decline in demand for many homogeneous goods. For producers of homogeneous goods, when demand falls, these producers have more of an incentive to maintain output and cut prices, in order to spread out the high fixed costs these producers faced (i.e. lowering cost per unit) and the desire to exploit efficiencies of maximum volume production. However, during the Panic of 1893, the fall in demand led to a steep fall in prices.

Another economic model proposed by Naomi R. Lamoreaux for explaining the steep price falls is to view the involved firms acting as monopolies in their respective markets. As quasi-monopolists, firms set quantity where marginal cost equals marginal revenue and price where this quantity intersects demand. When the Panic of 1893 hit, demand fell and along with demand, the firm’s marginal revenue fell as well. Given high fixed costs, the new price was below average total cost, resulting in a loss. However, also being in a high fixed costs industry, these costs can be spread out through greater production (i.e. higher quantity produced). To return to the quasi-monopoly model, in order for a firm to earn profit, firms would steal part of another firm’s market share by dropping their price slightly and producing to the point where higher quantity and lower price exceeded their average total cost. As other firms joined this practice, prices began falling everywhere and a price war ensued.[33]

One strategy to keep prices high and to maintain profitability was for producers of the same good to collude with each other and form associations, also known as cartels. These cartels were thus able to raise prices right away, sometimes more than doubling prices. However, these prices set by cartels provided only a short-term solution because cartel members would cheat on each other by setting a lower price than the price set by the cartel. Also, the high price set by the cartel would encourage new firms to enter the industry and offer competitive pricing, causing prices to fall once again. As a result, these cartels did not succeed in maintaining high prices for a period of more than a few years. The most viable solution to this problem was for firms to merge, through horizontal integration, with other top firms in the market in order to control a large market share and thus successfully set a higher price.[citation needed]

Long-run factors[edit]

In the long run, due to desire to keep costs low, it was advantageous for firms to merge and reduce their transportation costs thus producing and transporting from one location rather than various sites of different companies as in the past. Low transport costs, coupled with economies of scale also increased firm size by two- to fourfold during the second half of the nineteenth century. In addition, technological changes prior to the merger movement within companies increased the efficient size of plants with capital intensive assembly lines allowing for economies of scale. Thus improved technology and transportation were forerunners to the Great Merger Movement. In part due to competitors as mentioned above, and in part due to the government, however, many of these initially successful mergers were eventually dismantled. The U.S. government passed the Sherman Act in 1890, setting rules against price fixing and monopolies. Starting in the 1890s with such cases as Addyston Pipe and Steel Company v. United States, the courts attacked large companies for strategizing with others or within their own companies to maximize profits. Price fixing with competitors created a greater incentive for companies to unite and merge under one name so that they were not competitors anymore and technically not price fixing.

The economic history has been divided into Merger Waves based on the merger activities in the business world as:

PeriodNameFacet [34]
1893–1904First WaveHorizontal mergers
1919–1929Second WaveVertical mergers
1955–1970Third WaveDiversified conglomerate mergers
1974–1989Fourth WaveCo-generic mergers; Hostile takeovers; Corporate Raiding
1993–2000Fifth WaveCross-border mergers, mega-mergers
2003–2008Sixth WaveGlobalisation, Shareholder Activism, Private Equity, LBO
2014-Seventh WaveGeneric/balanced, horizontal mergers of Western companies acquiring emerging market resource producers

Objectives in more recent merger waves[edit]

During the third merger wave (1965–1989), corporate marriages involved more diverse companies. Acquirers more frequently bought into different industries. Sometimes this was done to smooth out cyclical bumps, to diversify, the hope being that it would hedge an investment portfolio.

Starting in the fifth merger wave (1992–1998) and continuing today, companies are more likely to acquire in the same business, or close to it, firms that complement and strengthen an acquirer’s capacity to serve customers.

In recent decades however, cross-sector convergence[35] has become more common. For example, retail companies are buying tech or e-commerce firms to acquire new markets and revenue streams. It has been reported that convergence will remain a key trend in M&A activity through 2015 and onward.

Buyers aren’t necessarily hungry for the target companies’ hard assets. Some are more interested in acquiring thoughts, methodologies, people and relationships. Paul Graham recognized this in his 2005 essay 'Hiring is Obsolete', in which he theorizes that the free market is better at identifying talent, and that traditional hiring practices do not follow the principles of free market because they depend a lot upon credentials and university degrees. Graham was probably the first to identify the trend in which large companies such as Google, Yahoo! or Microsoft were choosing to acquire startups instead of hiring new recruits,[36] a process known as acqui-hiring.

Many companies are being bought for their patents, licenses, market share, name brand, research staff, methods, customer base, or culture. Soft capital, like this, is very perishable, fragile, and fluid. Integrating it usually takes more finesse and expertise than integrating machinery, real estate, inventory and other tangibles.

Largest Deals in history[edit]

The top ten largest deals in M&A history cumulate to a total value of 1,118,963 mil. USD. (1.118 tril. USD).[37]

Date AnnouncedAcquiror NameAcquiror Mid IndustryAcquiror NationTarget NameTarget Mid IndustryTarget NationValue of Transaction ($mil)
11/14/1999Vodafone AirTouch PLCWirelessUnited KingdomMannesmann AGWirelessGermany202,785.13
01/10/2000America Online IncInternet Software & ServicesUnited StatesTime WarnerMotion Pictures / Audio VisualUnited States164,746.86
06/26/2015Altice SaCableLuxembourgAltice SaCableLuxembourg145,709.25
09/02/2013Verizon Communications IncTelecommunications ServicesUnited StatesVerizon Wireless IncWirelessUnited States130,298.32
08/29/2007ShareholdersOther FinancialsSwitzerlandPhilip Morris Intl IncTobaccoSwitzerland107,649.95
09/16/2015Anheuser-Busch InBev SA/NVFood and BeverageBelgiumSABMiller PLCFood and BeverageUnited Kingdom101,475.79
04/25/2007RFS Holdings BVOther FinancialsNetherlandsABN-AMRO Holding NVBanksNetherlands98,189.19
11/04/1999Pfizer IncPharmaceuticalsUnited StatesWarner-Lambert CoPharmaceuticalsUnited States89,167.72
22/10/2016AT&TMediaUnited StatesTime WarnerMediaUnited States88,400
12/01/1998Exxon CorpOil & GasUnited StatesMobil CorpOil & GasUnited States78,945.79

Cross-border[edit]

Introduction[edit]

In a study conducted in 2000 by Lehman Brothers, it was found that, on average, large M&A deals cause the domestic currency of the target corporation to appreciate by 1% relative to the acquirer's local currency. Until 2018, around 280.472 cross-border deals have been conducted, which cumulates to a total value of almost 24,069 bil. USD.[38]

The rise of globalization has exponentially increased the necessity for agencies such as the Mergers and Acquisitions International Clearing (MAIC), trust accounts and securities clearing services for Like-Kind Exchanges for cross-border M&A.[citation needed] On a global basis, the value of cross-border mergers and acquisitions rose seven-fold during the 1990s.[39] In 1997 alone, there were over 2,333 cross-border transactions, worth a total of approximately $298 billion.The vast literature on empirical studies over value creation in cross-border M&A is not conclusive, but points to higher returns in cross-border M&As compared to domestic ones when the acquirer firm has the capability to exploit resources and knowledge of the target's firm and of handling challenges.In China, for example, securing regulatory approval can be complex due to an extensive group of various stakeholders at each level of government. In the United Kingdom, acquirers may face pension regulators with significant powers, in addition to an overall M&A environment that is generally more seller-friendly than the U.S. Nonetheless, the current surge in global cross-border M&A has been called the 'New Era of Global Economic Discovery'.[40]

In little more than a decade, M&A deals in China increased by a factor of 20, from 69 in 2000 to more than 1,300 in 2013.

In 2014, Europe registered its highest levels of M&A deal activity since the financial crisis. Driven by U.S. and Asian acquirers, inbound M&A, at $320.6 billion, reached record highs by both deal value and deal count since 2001.

Approximately 23 percent of the 416 M&A deals announced in the U.S. M&A market in 2014 involved non-U.S. acquirers.

For 2016, market uncertainties, including Brexit and the potential reform from a U.S. Presidential election, contributed to cross-border M&A activity lagging roughly 20% behind 2015 activity.

In 2017, the controverse trend which started in 2015, decreasing total value but rising total number of cross border deals, kept going. Compared on a year on year basis (2016-2017), the total number of cross border deals decreased by -4.2%, while cumulated value increased by 0.6%.[41]

Even mergers of companies with headquarters in the same country can often be considered international in scale and require MAIC custodial services. For example, when Boeing acquired McDonnell Douglas, the two American companies had to integrate operations in dozens of countries around the world (1997). This is just as true for other apparently 'single-country' mergers, such as the 29 billion-dollar merger of Swiss drug makers Sandoz and Ciba-Geigy (now Novartis).

In emerging countries[edit]

M&A practice in emerging countries differs from more mature economies, although transaction management and valuation tools (e.g. DCF, comparables) share a common basic methodology. In China, India or Brazil for example, differences affect the formation of asset price and on the structuring of deals. Profitability expectations (e.g. shorter time horizon, no terminal value due to low visibility) and risk represented by a discount rate must both be properly adjusted.[42] In a M&A perspective, differences between emerging and more mature economies include: i) a less developed system of property rights, ii) less reliable financial information, iii) cultural differences in negotiations, and iv) a higher degree of competition for the best targets.

  • Property rights:[43] the capacity to transfer property rights and legally enforce the protection of such rights after payment may be questionable. Property transfer through the Stock Purchase Agreement can be imperfect (e.g. no real warranties) and even reversible (e.g. one of the multiple administrative authorizations needed not granted after closing) leading to situations where costly remedial actions may be necessary. When the rule of law is not established, corruption can be a rampant problem.
  • Information:[44] documentation delivered to a buyer may be scarce with a limited level of reliability. As an example, double sets of accounting are common practice and blur the capacity to form a correct judgment. Running valuation on such basis bears the risk to lead to erroneous conclusions. Therefore, building a reliable knowledge base on observable facts and on the result of focused due diligences, such as recurring profitability measured by EBITDA, is a good starting point.
  • Negotiation:[45] “Yes” may not be synonym that the parties have reached an agreement. Getting immediately to the point may not be considered appropriate in some cultures and even considered rude. The negotiations may continue to the last minute, sometimes even after the deal has been officially closed, if the seller keeps some leverage, like a minority stake, in the divested entity. Therefore, establishing a strong local business network before starting acquisitions is usually a prerequisite to get to know trustable parties to deal with and have allies.
  • Competition: the race to acquire the best companies in an emerging economy can generate a high degree of competition and inflate transaction prices, as a consequence of limited available targets. This may push for poor management decisions; before investment, time is always needed to build a reliable set of information on the competitive landscape.

If not properly dealt with, these factors will likely have adverse consequences on return-on-investment (ROI) and create difficulties in day-to-day business operations. It is advisable that M&A tools designed for mature economies are not directly used in emerging markets without some adjustment. M&A teams need time to adapt and understand the key operating differences between their home environment and their new market.

Failure[edit]

Despite the goal of performance improvement, results from mergers and acquisitions (M&A) are often disappointing compared with results predicted or expected. Numerous empirical studies show high failure rates of M&A deals. Studies are mostly focused on individual determinants. A book by Thomas Straub (2007) 'Reasons for frequent failure in Mergers and Acquisitions'[46] develops a comprehensive research framework that bridges different perspectives and promotes an understanding of factors underlying M&A performance in business research and scholarship. The study should help managers in the decision making process. The first important step towards this objective is the development of a common frame of reference that spans conflicting theoretical assumptions from different perspectives. On this basis, a comprehensive framework is proposed with which to understand the origins of M&A performance better and address the problem of fragmentation by integrating the most important competing perspectives in respect of studies on M&A. Furthermore, according to the existing literature, relevant determinants of firm performance are derived from each dimension of the model. For the dimension strategic management, the six strategic variables: market similarity, market complementarities, production operation similarity, production operation complementarities, market power, and purchasing power were identified as having an important effect on M&A performance. For the dimension organizational behavior, the variables acquisition experience, relative size, and cultural differences were found to be important. Finally, relevant determinants of M&A performance from the financial field were acquisition premium, bidding process, and due diligence. Three different ways in order to best measure post M&A performance are recognized: synergy realization, absolute performance, and finally relative performance.

Employee turnover contributes to M&A failures. The turnover in target companies is double the turnover experienced in non-merged firms for the ten years after the merger.[citation needed]

Major M&A[edit]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^Wang, William Yu Chung; Pauleen,, David; Chan, HingKai. 'Facilitating the merger of multinational companies A case study of the Global Virtual Enterprise'. Journal of Global Information Management, (2013), 21(1), 42-58.
  2. ^Stemler, Gregory; Welch, Shea; Johnson, Jeff; Mims, John; Davison, Brian. 'Methods for Developing a Rigorous Pre-Deal M&A Strategy'. Transaction Advisors. ISSN2329-9134.(Subscription required.)
  3. ^Derek van der Plaat (9 September 2013). 'Four Companies That Know How to Acquire'. Private Company Mergers and Acquisitions. Retrieved 18 February 2015.[self-published source?]
  4. ^Investment banking explained pp. 223-224
  5. ^Harwood, 2005
  6. ^The Economist, 'The new rules of attraction', 15 Nov 2014
  7. ^Rumyantseva, Maria, Grzegorz Gurgul, and Ellen Enkel. 'Knowledge Integration after Mergers & Acquisitions.' University of Mississippi Business Department. University of Mississippi, July 2002.
  8. ^Ranft, Annette L., and Michael D. Lord. 'Acquiring new technologies and capabilities: A grounded model of acquisition implementation.' Organization science 13.4 (2002): 420-441.
  9. ^Moore, Jim. 'Get acquired! An idiot's guide to technology M&A'. Retrieved 19 August 2013.
  10. ^ ab'Mergers & Acquisitions Quick Reference Guide'(PDF). McKenna Long & Aldridge LLP. Retrieved 19 August 2013.
  11. ^Griffin, William F. 'Tax Aspects of Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions'(PDF). Davis Malm & D'Agostine, P.C. Archived from the original(PDF) on 11 May 2013. Retrieved 19 August 2013.
  12. ^Barusch, Ronald. 'WSJ M&A 101: A Guide to Merger Agreements'. WSJ Deal Journal. Retrieved 19 August 2013.
  13. ^Collan, Mikael; Kinnunen Jani (2011). 'A Procedure for the Rapid Pre-acquisition Screening of Target Companies Using the Pay-off Method for Real Option Valuation'. Journal of Real Options and Strategy. 4 (1): 117–141.
  14. ^King, D. R.; Slotegraaf, R.; Kesner, I. (2008). 'Performance implications of firm resource interactions in the acquisition of R&D-intensive firms'. Organization Science. 19 (2): 327–340. doi:10.1287/orsc.1070.0313.
  15. ^Maddigan, Ruth; Zaima, Janis (1985). 'The Profitability of Vertical Integration'. Managerial and Decision Economics. 6 (3): 178–179. doi:10.1002/mde.4090060310.
  16. ^Ng, Artie W.; Chatzkel, Jay; Lau, K.F.; Macbeth, Douglas (2012-07-20). 'Dynamics of Chinese emerging multinationals in cross‐border mergers and acquisitions'. Journal of Intellectual Capital. 13 (3): 416–438. doi:10.1108/14691931211248963. ISSN1469-1930.
  17. ^Zhang, Yu; Wu, Xianming; Zhang, Hao; Lyu, Chan; Zhang, Yu; Wu, Xianming; Zhang, Hao; Lyu, Chan (2018-05-30). 'Cross-Border M&A and the Acquirers' Innovation Performance: An Empirical Study in China'. Sustainability. 10 (6): 1796. doi:10.3390/su10061796.
  18. ^King, D. R.; Dalton, D. R.; Daily, C. M.; Covin, J. G. (2004). 'Meta-analyses of Post-acquisition Performance: Indications of Unidentified Moderators'. Strategic Management Journal. 25 (2): 187–200. doi:10.1002/smj.371.
  19. ^'RECOMMENDED CASH OFFER FOR EIDOS PLC BY SQEX LTD. TO BE EFFECTED BY MEANS OF A SCHEME OF ARRANGEMENT UNDER THE UK COMPANIES ACT 2006'(PDF). Square Enix. 12 February 2009. Retrieved 16 February 2018.
  20. ^'From Software acquired by Japanese publisher Kadokawa Corporation'. Engadget. Retrieved 2017-12-10.
  21. ^'Notice Concerning Exchange of Shares to Convert Sammy NetWorks Co., Ltd., SEGA TOYS CO., LTD. and TMS ENTERTAINMENT, LTD. into Wholly Owned Subsidiaries of SEGA SAMMY HOLDINGS INC'(PDF). Sega Sammy Holdings Inc. 27 August 2010. Retrieved 9 January 2017.
  22. ^ ab'MERGER & CONSOLIDATION: OVERVIEW'. www.shsu.edu. Retrieved 2017-12-10.
  23. ^In re Cox Communications, Inc. Shareholders Litig., 879 A.2d 604, 606 (Del. Ch. 2005).
  24. ^Hof, Robert. 'Attention Startups: Here's How To Get Acqui-Hired By Google, Yahoo Or Twitter'. Forbes. Retrieved 9 January 2014.
  25. ^'Start-Ups Get Snapped Up for Their Talent'. Wall Street Journal.Missing or empty url= (help); access-date= requires url= (help)
  26. ^'M&A by Transaction Type - IMAA-Institute'. IMAA-Institute. Retrieved 2016-12-22.
  27. ^'NewsBeast And Other Merger Name Options « Merriam Associates, Inc. Brand Strategies'. Merriamassociates.com. Archived from the original on 2012-11-06. Retrieved 2012-12-18.
  28. ^ ab'Caterpillar's New Legs—Acquiring the Bucyrus International Brand « Merriam Associates, Inc. Brand Strategies'. Merriamassociates.com. Archived from the original on 2012-10-30. Retrieved 2012-12-18.
  29. ^De Jong, Abe; Gelderblom, Oscar; Jonker, Joost (2010), 'An Admiralty for Asia: Isaac le Maire and Conflicting Conceptions About the Corporate Governance of the VOC'. (Working Paper Erasmus Research Institute of Management, 2010). Gelderblom, de Jong, and Jonker (2010)'(..) In 1597 Van Oldenbarnevelt started pushing for a consolidation because the continuing competition threatened to compromise the Dutch fight against Spain and Portugal in Asia (Den Heijer 2005, 41). The companies of Middelburg and Veere followed the Amsterdam example and merged into one Verenigde Zeeuwse Compagnie in 1600. The idea for a merger between the all companies, first considered in 1599, then reappeared, given new momentum by the emergence of the East India Company in Britain. (..) Negotiations between the Dutch companies took a long time because of conflicting demands. Firstly, the Estates General wanted the merger to secure a strong Dutch presence in Asia. The hot rivalry between the voorcompagnieën undermined the country's fragile political unity and economic prosperity, and seriously limited the prospects of competing successfully against other Asian traders from Europe. By attacking the Luso-Hispanic overseas empire, a large, united company would also help in the ongoing war against the Spanish Habsburgs. Initially Van Oldenbarnevelt thought of no more than two or three manned strongholds (Van Deventer 1862, 301), but the Estates General wanted an offensive (Van Brakel 1908, 20-21).'
  30. ^Gelderblom, Oscar; de Jong, Abe; Jonker, Joost (2011), 'An Admiralty for Asia: Business Organization and the Evolution of Corporate Governance in the Dutch Republic, 1590–1640,'; in J.G. Koppell (ed.), Origins of Shareholder Advocacy. (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2011), pp. 29–70. Gelderblom, Jonker & de Jong (2010): 'The hot rivalry between the voorcompagnieën undermined the country's fragile political unity and economic prosperity, and seriously limited the prospects of competing successfully against other Asian traders from Europe. .. According to Willem Usselincx, a large merchant well versed in the intercontinental trade, the VOC charter was drafted by bewindhebbers bent on defending their own interests and the Estates General had allowed that to pass so as to achieve the desired merger (Van Rees 1868, 410). An agreement was finally reached on March 20th, 1602, after which the Estates General issued a charter granting a monopoly on the Asian trade for 21 years (Gaastra 2009, 21-23).'
  31. ^Unoki, Ko (2012), 'A Seafaring Empire,'; in Mergers, Acquisitions and Global Empires: Tolerance, Diversity and the Success of M&A, by Ko Unoki. (New York: Routledge, 2013), pp. 39–64
  32. ^'Monte dei Paschi di Siena Bank About us History The Lorraine reform'. 2009-03-17. Retrieved 2012-12-18.
  33. ^Lamoreaux, Naomi R. 'The great merger movement in American business, 1895-1904.' Cambridge University Press, 1985.
  34. ^'Insights KPMG ZA'. KPMG. 2016-11-15. Retrieved 2017-12-11.
  35. ^'Corporate America's Dealmakers Are Cross-Pollinating'. www.bloomberg.com. Retrieved 2018-10-18.
  36. ^'Hiring is Obsolete'. Retrieved 18 February 2015.
  37. ^'M&A Statistics - Worldwide, Regions, Industries & Countries'. Institute for Mergers, Acquisitions and Alliances (IMAA). Retrieved 2018-02-28.
  38. ^'M&A by Transaction Type - Institute for Mergers, Acquisitions and Alliances (IMAA)'. Institute for Mergers, Acquisitions and Alliances (IMAA). Retrieved 2018-02-27.
  39. ^United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 2000, World Investment Report 2000: Cross-border Mergers and Acquisitions and Development (Overview), New York and Geneva, p. 10.
  40. ^Ayisi-Cromwell, M. 'The New Era of Global Economic Discovery: Opportunities and Challenges'. Thomson Reuters Emerging Markets Investment Forum. New York, NY. 19 Sep. 2012. Chairman’s Opening Remarks.
  41. ^'M&A by Transaction Type - IMAA-Institute'. IMAA-Institute. Retrieved 2018-02-22.
  42. ^Donald R. Lessart. “Incorporting Country risk in the valuation of offshore projects”, MIT, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, volume 9, number 3, 1996
  43. ^Alchian, Armen, and Harold Demsetz. “The Property Rights Paradigm.” Journal of Economic History 33, no. 1 (1973): 16–27
  44. ^Feng Chen, Ole-Kristian Hope, Qingyuan Li, Xin Wang. “The Property Rights Paradigm.”Financial Reporting Quality and Investment Efficiency of Private Firms in Emerging Markets, working paper, University of Toronto, Wuhan University Chinese University of Hong Kong, July 6, 2010
  45. ^as an illustration, Laurence J. Brahm. “The art of the deal in China.” Tuttle Publishing, April 2007, 160 pages, ISBN0804839026
  46. ^[Straub, Thomas (2007). Reasons for frequent failure in Mergers and Acquisitions: A comprehensive analysis. Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag (DUV), Gabler Edition Wissenschaft. ISBN978-3-8350-0844-1.]

Further reading[edit]

  • Denison, Daniel, Hooijberg, Robert, Lane, Nancy, Lief, Colleen, (2012). Leading Culture Change in Global Organizations. 'Creating One Culture Out of Many', chapter 4. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. ISBN9780470908846
  • Aharon, D.Y.; Gavious, I.; Yosef, R. (2010). 'Stock market bubble effects on mergers and acquisitions'(PDF). The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance. 50 (4): 456–470. doi:10.1016/j.qref.2010.05.002.
  • Cartwright, Susan; Schoenberg, Richard (2006). 'Thirty Years of Mergers and Acquisitions Research: Recent Advances and Future Opportunities'(PDF). British Journal of Management. 17 (S1): S1–S5. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8551.2006.00475.x.
  • Bartram, Söhnke M.; Burns, Natasha; Helwege, Jean (September 2013). 'Foreign Currency Exposure and Hedging: Evidence from Foreign Acquisitions'. Quarterly Journal of Finance. forthcoming. CiteSeerX10.1.1.580.8086. SSRN1116409.CS1 maint: Multiple names: authors list (link)
  • Close, John Weir. A Giant Cow-tipping by Savages: The Boom, Bust, and Boom Culture of M&A. New York: Palgrave Macmilla. ISBN9780230341814. OCLC828246072.
  • Coispeau, Olivier; Luo, Stephane (2015). Mergers & Acquisitions and Partnerships in China. Singapore: World Scientific. p. 311. ISBN9789814641029. OCLC898052215.
  • DePamphilis, Donald (2008). Mergers, Acquisitions, and Other Restructuring Activities. New York: Elsevier, Academic Press. p. 740. ISBN978-0-12-374012-0.
  • Douma, Sytse & Hein Schreuder (2013). 'Economic Approaches to Organizations', chapter 13. 5th edition. London: Pearson. ISBN0273735292ISBN9780273735298
  • Fleuriet, Michel (2008). Investment Banking explained: An insider's guide to the industry. New York, NY: McGraw Hill. ISBN978-0-07-149733-6.
  • Harwood, I. A. (2006). 'Confidentiality constraints within mergers and acquisitions: gaining insights through a 'bubble' metaphor'. British Journal of Management. 17 (4): 347–359. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8551.2005.00440.x.
  • Locke, Bryan; Singh, Harsh; Chung, Joanna; Ferguson, John J. 'Selling Acquisitions to Institutional Investors, Proxy Handlers, Regulators, and the Financial Media'. Transaction Advisors. ISSN2329-9134.
  • Locke, Firmex; Inc, Divestopedia; Inc. 'The 2017 M&A Fee Guide'. Firmex & Divestopedia.
  • Popp, Karl Michael (2013). Mergers and Acquisitions in the Software Industry - foundations of due diligence. Norderstedt: Books on demand. ISBN978-3-7322-4381-5.
  • Reddy, K.S., Nangia, V.K., & Agrawal, R. (2014). The 2007-2008 global financial crisis, and cross-border mergers and acquisitions: A 26-nation exploratory study. Global Journal of Emerging Market Economies, 6(3), 257-281. http://eme.sagepub.com/content/6/3/257.short
  • Reddy, K.S.; Nangia, V.K.; Agrawal, R. (2013). 'Indian economic-policy reforms, bank mergers, and lawful proposals: The ex-ante and ex-post 'lookup''. Journal of Policy Modeling. 35 (4): 601–622. doi:10.1016/j.jpolmod.2012.12.001.
  • Reddy, K.S.; Agrawal, R.; Nangia, V.K. (2013). 'Reengineering, crafting and comparing business valuation models-the advisory exemplar'. International Journal of Commerce and Management. 23 (3): 216–241. doi:10.1108/IJCoMA-07-2011-0018.
  • Reifenberger, Sabine (28 December 2012). M&A Market: The New Normal. CFO Insight
  • Rosenbaum, Joshua; Joshua Pearl (2009). Investment Banking: Valuation, Leveraged Buyouts, and Mergers & Acquisitions. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons. ISBN0-470-44220-4.
  • Scott, Andy (2008). China Briefing: Mergers and Acquisitions in China (2nd ed.).
  • Straub, Thomas (2007). Reasons for frequent failure in Mergers and Acquisitions: A comprehensive analysis. Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag (DUV), Gabler Edition Wissenschaft. ISBN978-3-8350-0844-1.
Retrieved from 'https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Mergers_and_acquisitions&oldid=895895666'
Part of a series on
Economic systems
  • Capitalist
  • Religious
  • Socialist
  • Traditionalist
  • Asian
  • European
  • Latin America
  • Market
  • Planning
  • Self-managed

Attention economics is an approach to the management of information that treats human attention as a scarce commodity, and applies economic theory to solve various information management problems. Put simply by Matthew Crawford, 'Attention is a resource—a person has only so much of it.'[1]

In this perspective Thomas H. Davenport and J. C. Beck define the concept of attention as:

Attention is focused mental engagement on a particular item of information. Items come into our awareness, we attend to a particular item, and then we decide whether to act (2001)

As content has grown increasingly abundant and immediately available, attention becomes the limiting factor in the consumption of information.[2]
A strong trigger of this effect is that the mental capability of humans is limited and the receptiveness of information is hence limited as well. Attention is used to filter the most important information by the human brain from a large pool of information surrounding the human in the digital age.[3]

A number of software applications either explicitly or implicitly take attention economy into consideration in their user interface design, based on the realization that if it takes the user too long to locate something, they will find it through another application. This is done, for instance, by creating filters to make sure the first content a viewer sees is relevant, of interest, or with the approval of demographics.[4] An attention-based advertising scheme may describe measuring the number of 'eyeballs' by which content is seen.[5]

  • 4Applications
    • 4.2Controlling information pollution

History[edit]

Herbert A. Simon[6] was perhaps the first person to articulate the concept of attention economics when he wrote:

[I]n an information-rich world, the wealth of information means a dearth of something else: a scarcity of whatever it is that information consumes. What information consumes is rather obvious: it consumes the attention of its recipients. Hence a wealth of information creates a poverty of attention and a need to allocate that attention efficiently among the overabundance of information sources that might consume it. (Simon 1971, pp. 40–41)

He noted that many designers of information systems incorrectly represented their design problem as information scarcity rather than attention scarcity, and as a result they built systems that excelled at providing more and more information to people, when what was really needed were systems that excelled at filtering out unimportant or irrelevant information (1996).

In recent years, Simon's characterization of the problem of information overload as an economic one has become more popular. Business strategists such as Thomas H. Davenport or Michael H. Goldhaber have adopted the term 'attention economy' (Davenport & Beck 2001).

Some writers have even speculated that 'attention transactions' will replace financial transactions as the focus of our economic system (Goldhaber 1997, Franck 1999). Information systems researchers have also adopted the idea, and are beginning to investigate mechanism designs which build on the idea of creating property rights in attention (see Applications).

Intangibles[edit]

According to digital culture expert Kevin Kelly, the modern attention economy is increasingly one where the consumer product costs virtually nothing to reproduce and the problem facing the supplier of the product lies in adding valuable intangibles that cannot be reproduced at any cost. He identifies these intangibles as:[7]

Economics
  1. Immediacy - priority access, immediate delivery
  2. Personalization - tailored just for you
  3. Interpretation - support and guidance
  4. Authenticity - how can you be sure it is the real thing?
  5. Accessibility - wherever, whenever
  6. Embodiment - books, live music
  7. Patronage - 'paying simply because it feels good',
  8. Findability - 'When there are millions of books, millions of songs, millions of films, millions of applications, millions of everything requesting our attention — and most of it free — being found is valuable.'

Social attention, collective attention[edit]

Attention economy is also relevant to the social sphere. More specifically, long term attention can also be considered according to the attention that a person dedicates managing its interactions with others. Dedicating too much attention to these interactions can lead to 'social interaction overload', i.e. when people are overwhelmed in managing their relationships with others, for instance in the context of social network services in which people are the subject of a high level of social solicitations. Digital media and the internet facilitate participation in this economy, by creating new channels for distributing attention. Ordinary people are now empowered to reach a wide audience by publishing their own content and commenting on the content of others.[8]

Social attention can also be associated to collective attention, i.e. how 'attention to novel items propagates and eventually fades among large populations' (2007).

Applications[edit]

In advertising[edit]

'Attention economics' treats a potential consumer's attention as a resource.[9] Traditional media advertisers followed a model that suggested consumers went through a linear process they called AIDA - Attention, Interest, Desire and Action. Attention is therefore a major and the first stage in the process of converting non-consumers. Since the cost to transmit advertising to consumers is now sufficiently low that more ads can be transmitted to a consumer (e.g. via online advertising) than the consumer can process, the consumer's attention becomes the scarce resource to be allocated. Dolgin also states that a superfluidity of information may hinder the decision making of an individual who keeps searching and comparing products as long as it promises to provide more than it is using up.[10]

Controlling information pollution[edit]

One application treats various forms of information (spam, advertising) as a form of pollution or 'detrimental externality'. In economics an externality is a by-product of a production process that imposes burdens (or supplies benefits), to parties other than the intended consumer of a commodity. For example; air and water pollution are ‘negative’ externalities which impose burdens on society and the environment.

A market-based approach to controlling externalities was outlined in Ronald Coase's The Problem of Social Cost (1960). This evolved from an article on the Federal Communications Commission (1959), in which Coase claimed that radio frequency interference is a negative externality that could be controlled by the creation of property rights.

Coase's approach to the management of externalities requires the careful specification of property rights and a set of rules for the initial allocation of the rights. Once this has been achieved, a market mechanism can theoretically manage the externality problem. The solution is not necessarily simple in its application to media content (1996).

E-mail spam[edit]

Sending huge numbers of e-mail messages costs spammers very little, since the costs of e-mail messages are spread out over the internet service providers that distribute them (and the recipients who must spend attention dealing with them). Thus sending out as much spam as possible is a rational strategy: even if only 0.001% of recipients (1 in 100,000) is converted into a sale, a spam campaign can be profitable[citation needed]. Spammers are demanding valuable attention from potential customers, but they are avoiding paying a fair price for this attention due to the current architecture of e-mail systems.

One way this might be implemented is by charging senders a small fee per e-mail sent, often referred to as a 'Sender Bond.' It might be close to free for an advertiser to send a single e-mail message to a single recipient, but sending that same e-mail to 1,000 recipients would cost him 1,000 times as much. A 2002 experiment with this kind of usage-based e-mail pricing found that it caused senders to spend more effort targeting their messages to recipients who would find them relevant, thus shifting the cost of deciding whether a given e-mail message is relevant from the recipient to the sender[citation needed].

Closely related is the idea of selling 'interrupt rights,' or small fees for the right to demand one's attention. The cost of these rights could vary according to the person who is interrupted: interrupt rights for the CEO of a Fortune 500 company would presumably be extraordinarily expensive, while those of a high school student might be lower. Costs could also vary for an individual depending on context, perhaps rising during the busy holiday season and falling during the dog days of summer. Those who are interrupted could decline to collect their fees from friends, family, and other welcome interrupters.

Another idea in this vein is the creation of 'attention bonds,' small warranties that some information will not be a waste of the recipient's time, placed into escrow at the time of sending. Like the granters of interrupt rights, receivers could cash in their bonds to signal to the sender that a given communication was a waste of their time or elect not to cash them in to signal that more communication would be welcome.

Supporters of attention markets for controlling spam claim that their solutions are superior to the alternatives for managing uses of information systems on which there is no consensus on the question of whether it is pollution or not.[citation needed] For example, the use of e-mail or text messages for rallying political support or by non-profit charitable organizations may be considered spam by some users but legitimate use by others. Laws against spam put the power to make this decision in the hands of government, while technological solutions like filtering technologies put it in the hands of private companies or technologically savvy users. Supporters assert that a neoliberal market-based solution allows the possibility of individual negotiation over the worth of a given message rather than a unilateral decision by a controlling party[citation needed].

Web spam[edit]

As search engines have become the primary means for finding and accessing information on the web, high rankings in the results for certain queries have become valuable commodities, due to the ability of search engines to focus searchers' attention. Like other information systems, web search is vulnerable to pollution: 'Because the Web environment contains profit seeking ventures, attention getting strategies evolve in response to search engine algorithms' (Page 1998). It is estimated that successful exploitation of such strategies, known as web spam, is a potential $4.5 billion per year business (2004).

Since most major search engines now rely on some form of PageRank (recursive counting of hyperlinks to a site) to determine search result rankings, a gray market in the creation and trading of hyperlinks has emerged. Participants in this market engage in a variety of practices known as link spamming, link farming, and reciprocal linking.

Another issue, similar to the issue discussed above of whether or not to consider political e-mail campaigns as spam, is what to do about politically motivated link campaigns or Google bombs (2005). Currently the major search engines do not treat these as web spam, but this is a decision made unilaterally by private companies. There is no opportunity for negotiation over the question of what is an appropriate use of attention expressed through hyperlinking. It remains to be seen whether a market-based approach might provide more flexible handling of these gray areas.

Sales lead generation[edit]

The paid inclusion model, as well as more pervasive advertising networks like Yahoo! Publisher Network and Google's AdSense, work by treating consumer attention as the property of the search engine (in the case of paid inclusion) or the publisher (in the case of advertising networks). This is somewhat different from the anti-spam uses of property rights in attention, which treat an individual's attention as his or her own property.

See also[edit]

  • The Magical Number Seven, Plus or Minus Two (paper)
  • Tim Ferriss, low information diet[11]

References[edit]

  1. ^Crawford, Matthew B. (March 31, 2015). 'Introduction, Attention as a Cultural Problem'. The World Beyond Your Head: On Becoming an Individual in an Age of Distraction (hardcover) (1st ed.). Farrar, Straus and Giroux. p. 11. ISBN978-0374292980. In the main currents of psychological research, attention is a resource—a person has only so much of it.
  2. ^Media, Crowdcentric (2014-05-20). On! The Future of Now: Making Sense of Our Always On, Always Connected World. ISBN978-1483412429. Retrieved 2 June 2015.
  3. ^'Mega-Trend Attention Economy'. trendone.
  4. ^Iskold, Alex (March 1, 2007). 'The Attention Economy'. ReadWriteWeb.
  5. ^''Eyeball' marketing goes high tech'. TechRepublic. January 5, 2007.
  6. ^Simon (1971). 'DESIGNING ORGANIZATIONS FOR AN INFORMATION-RICH WORLD'. digitalcollections.library.cmu.edu. Retrieved 2018-12-14.
  7. ^Kelly, Kevin (February 5, 2008). 'BETTER THAN FREE'. The Edge.
  8. ^Jones, Rodney H.; Hafner, Christoph A. (2012). Understanding Digital Literacies. New York: Routledge. p. 90. ISBN9780415673167.
  9. ^Pedrycz, Witold; Chen, Shyi-Ming, eds. (9 December 2013). Social Networks: A Framework of Computational Intelligence. p. 229. ISBN978-3-319-02993-1. Retrieved 1 June 2015.
  10. ^Dolgin, Alexander (2008). The Economics of Symbolic Exchange. pp. 164–165. ISBN978-3-540-79883-5. Retrieved 1 June 2015.
  11. ^Ferriss, Tim. 'Low-Information Diet'. The Blog of Author Tim Ferriss. Retrieved 5 August 2015.

Further reading[edit]

  • Coase, R. H. (1959), 'The Federal Communications Commission'(PDF), Journal of Law and Economics, 2 (1): 1–40, CiteSeerX10.1.1.203.5622, doi:10.1086/466549, archived from the original(PDF) on 2013-11-07
  • Lanchester, John (August 2017), 'You Are the Product', London Review of Books, 39 (16): 3–10
  • Lanham, Richard (2006), The Economics of Attention: Style and Substance in the Age of Information
  • Schmid, H. (2009), Economy of Fascination: Dubai and Las Vegas as Themed Urban Landscapes, Stuttgart, Berlin: E. Schweizerbart science publishers, ISBN978-3-443-37014-5.
  • Tran, J. L. (2016), 'The Right to Attention', Indiana Law Journal, 91: 1023–62, SSRN2600463
  • Wu, Fang; Huberman, Bernardo (2007), 'Novelty and collective attention', Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 104 (17599): 17599–17601, arXiv:0704.1158, Bibcode:2007PNAS.10417599W, CiteSeerX10.1.1.90.7143, doi:10.1073/pnas.0704916104, PMC2077036, PMID17962416

External links[edit]

Retrieved from 'https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Attention_economy&oldid=889435036'